United in Diversity, Divided by Algorithms?A Cross-National Examination of the Role of Ad Delivery Algorithms
during the 2024 European Parliament Election


Fabio Votta, Simon Kruschinski, Mads Fuglsang Hove, Anamaria Dutceac Segesten, Márton Bene, Christina Gahn, Linn Sandberg, Jan Zilinsky,
Claes de Vreese, James P. Cross, Ruth Dassonneville, Tom Dobber, Benjamin Guinaudeau


Introduction

The health of representative democracy relies on competitive elections in which parties can meaningfully contest for voter support. Ensuring this requires a level playing field that offers political actors fair opportunities to reach and persuade the electorate. Traditionally regulatory frameworks have responded to this need by creating rules for financial expenditure and transparency obligations.

However, the rise of social media has transformed campaign strategies. Platforms like Facebook now offer powerful tools for voter outreach, particularly through targeted advertising. Yet unlike traditional media, online political advertising operates with minimal oversight (Helberger, Dobber, & de Vreese, 2021). The cost of political advertisements is determined by ad auctions, whose decision mechanisms are vague and opaque (Votta et al. 2024). We argue that this automation threatens political equality by introducing biases that can systematically favor certain parties and constituencies.

RQ1: How do prices for political ads vary?
RQ2: What factors influence price differences?

Design: Algorithm Audit Study

  • 2024 European Parliament election

  • 30 political parties in 8 countries (incl. 3 European parties, each advertising in 5 countries)

  • Facebook ads ran 7 days from April 29, 2024 - 1€ daily budget per ad (105€ per party, €525 for European parties)

  • Identical GOTV ads using official party accounts

  • Each Party X Country = 15 ads (3 audiences × 5 ad copies) - in total 630 ads

  • DV: Cost per 1,000 unique users reached (CPM)

3 targeting conditions:
– Interest in Politics
– Below-University Education
– No Targeting

3 potential influence factors:
– Market-level factors
– Party-level factors
– Account-level factors

GOTV ads used in Study

Main Results

Country Level Differences

Party variance

Large CPM differences across countries, with up to 332% between Denmark and Hungary. On average, countries differed by 56% despite identical ad content and budgets.

Party & Audience Level Differences

Party variance

Within countries, parties paid up to 27% more or less than others for the same ad. The average party-level difference was 4%. Deviations were largest when no audience was targeted. This translates into thousands of users reached more or less for the same budget.

The largest between-party differences can be observed in the Belgian regions of Wallonia and Flanders. In Flanders, Vooruit pays 27% more for the same ad compared to ECPM.

Multilevel Models: DV = Cost per 1,000 users

Coefficients Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Fixed Effects
Intercept 0.974*** (0.064) 0.966*** (0.137) 0.966*** (0.137) 0.998 (0.684)
Times Ad was Shown 0.651*** (0.053)
Engagements 0.008* (0.003)
Total Spent on Ad -0.101 (0.095)
Random Effects (SD)
Audience-Level Price SD 0.107 0.110 0.110 0.119
Within-Country Price SD 0.382 0.056 0.044 0.038
Country-Level Price SD 0.363 0.362 0.371
Party-Level Price SD 0.039 0.041

Note: Model 1 includes a random intercept for the target audience only. Model 2 adds a random intercept for each country. Model 3 introduces a nested random intercept structure for parties within countries. Model 4 adds fixed effects for ad engagement, total ad spend, and impressions. Random intercepts represent price variation by country, audience, and party. Within-country SD captures unexplained national variation.*** p < 0.001; ** p < 0.01; * p < 0.05.

Exploratory Findings


Price Differences by Age

Party variance

Reaching younger users (18–24) tends to be more expensive compared to reaching older age groups but pricing difference depends on party.


Price Differences by Gender

Party variance

Gender-based pricing shows no consistent pattern and varies substantially within different countries.

Note: exploratory graphs here include parties (in grey) that did not run ads at the same time or spend less so comparison should be careful.

What Correlates with Prices?

Multilevel Models: DV = Cost per 1,000 users

Party variance

Account-level factors such as recent and historical ad spending are positively associated with higher prices. This means larger spenders are charged more and smaller spenders are charged less.

Party-level patterns suggest that European party accounts and right-leaning parties may receive lower prices. Alignment between the party’s voter base and the reached audience (e.g., if the reached audience aligns with the voter base in terms of age and gender) is weakly associated with cost reductions, though coefficients are small and not always statistically significant.

Market-level factors show that larger audience sizes tend to face lower prices, possibly due to broader supply and/or reduced competition for views.

Conclusion

Unequal Playing Field: Algorithmic pricing introduces substantial variation in the cost of reaching voters. Even with identical content and budgets, these differences can distort political competition and influence which citizens are more likely to be reached or excluded.

Transparency Gap: Current regulation and transparency tools overwhelmingly focus on what content is shown and who is targeted. However, they neglect the crucial role of how ads are delivered by ad delivery algorithms. These systems not only shape prices, but also affect the final audience composition of political messages. Our findings suggest that platform-controlled delivery decisions can lead to systematic price and reach differences without advertisers’ knowledge, and without public accountability.

Policy Implications: While the Digital Services Act mandates transparency around political advertising, ad delivery algorithms remain a blind spot. Ad libraries should be extended to include metadata on optimization goals and delivery parameters. Crucially, platforms currently optimize ad delivery for commercial outcomes. This logic may be appropriate in consumer markets, for instance in cases where a company selling cat toys are not directly competing with one that sells dog toys. But political advertising is fundamentally different. Parties are competing for votes over the same electorate, which requires a fair and level playing field. Platforms should adapt their ad delivery infrastructure to reflect the distinct normative stakes of political advertising.

Our findings call for a shift from solely focusing on targeting criteria to also addressing the role of ad delivery algorithms. Without that, efforts to regulate digital campaigns remain incomplete and insufficient.